A
Case for Lower Top Marginal Tax Rates
There has been much discussion in
the popular press in the last few years about economic growth and income
inequality. Some economists and commentators have suggested that inequality is
a barrier to economic growth (Plumer, 2013) . In Kuznets’ canonical
formulation, inequality rises as per-capita income rises from low levels, but
begins to fall as per-capita income rises yet further (Figure 1) (Kuznets, 1955) . The argument of those who
believe inequality and growth are incompatible is both that the United States
economy is on the “right-hand side” of the Kuznets Curve, and that there is a
causal relationship that runs from inequality to growth. Evidence, however,
suggests that reducing the marginal tax rates for the top three brackets (currently
33, 35, and 39.6 percent) would increase gross domestic product (GDP). The
primary channel for this increase is the labor supply. Numerous studies
indicate that reducing top rates would incentivize workers to work more and for
non-participants to enter the labor force. For these reasons, I recommend a
reduction in the top three marginal income tax rates.
Barro and Redlick find that marginal
tax rate increases negatively impact GDP significantly. They found a tax
multiplier of approximately 1.1. While this value is unlikely to be robust for
marginal rates significantly different from current rates, the 1.1 value is
likely to hold for a decrease in rates as well. Barro and Redlick also argue
that a decrease in aggregate taxes has a higher multiplier, and therefore a
greater stimulative effect, than increases in government purchases, for which
the multiplier is less than one (Barro & Redlick, 2011) .
The 1986 Tax Reform Act (TRA), which
greatly reduced the top rates, provides a natural experiment that has been
studied by many researchers. Evans and Kenward estimate that labor supply would
increase by 3 percent, leading to a rise in output of 2 percent (Evans & Kenward, 1988) . Though they
attribute some of the increase in labor supply to the entrance of women into
the labor force, a similar effect could be observed today in the reversal of
the downward trend in labor-force participation, which has been falling since
the mid 1990s, and falling precipitously since 2008 (Figure 2).
Feldstein’s panel study of the TRA finds
that individuals’ response to this reduction included increasing labor supply (Feldstein, 1995) . This response to altered
incentives will lead to an increase in GDP if aggregate supply can be
approximated with a Cobb-Douglas production function (Bao Hong, 2008) . Feldstein also points out that
lower marginal rates encourage workers to take less of their compensation in
the form of untaxed perquisites (Feldstein, 1995) . This shift toward pecuniary
compensation likely reduces deadweight loss, as workers can more directly
satisfy their needs and desires with money wages than with non-wage benefits.
Heim’s panel study of the 2001 and
2003 tax law changes, which also reduced marginal rates on higher earners,
mirrors Feldstein’s findings. Heim found positive labor-supply effects,
especially among those with incomes above $500,000 per year. Like Feldstein’s,
Heim’s results imply that reversing the reductions would not likely increase
revenue, because workers whose taxes return to higher levels are more likely to
work less than to continue working the same amount (Heim, 2009) .
It is important to note that the period covered by Heim’s study, 1999-2005,
included a recession and subsequent recovery. It is therefore possible that his
findings are specifically relevant to current conditions. Further supporting
the results of Feldstein and Heim, McDaniel finds, in a study of fifteen OECD
countries over the period 1960-2004, that 80 percent of changes in hours worked
is attributable to changes in tax rates, with the relationship between hours
worked and tax rates always negative (McDaniel, 2011) .
Arnold, et al. find that replacing
income tax revenue with revenue from consumption taxes is beneficial to
economic growth. These consumption taxes could take the form of value-added
taxes and targeted taxes aimed at reducing environmentally damaging
consumption. They specifically cite sales tax reductions as growth-inhibiting. They find that reductions in the
top rates would spur productivity growth and entrepreneurship. They
specifically cite the progressivity of personal income taxes as a barrier to
growth (Arnold, et al., 2011) .
At a time when labor-force
participation is falling, it is sound policy to incentivize workers to remain
in or enter the labor force. Many studies have shown the efficacy of lower
marginal income tax rates in achieving this goal. Further, the effect is most
prominent on the highest earners. For this reason, I advocate a reduction of
the top three marginal income tax brackets.
Figures
Figure
1: Theoretical Kuznets Curve (as described in (Kuznets, 1955) )
Figure
2: Labor Force Participation 1993-2014 (Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, 2014)
Works
Cited
Arnold,
J. M., Brys, B., Heady, C., Johansson, A., Schwellnus, C., & Vartia, L.
(2011). Tax Policy for Economic Recovery and Growth. The Economic Journal,
F59-F80.
Bao Hong, T.
(2008, November 20). Cobb-Douglas Production Function. Retrieved
February 2, 2014, from João Luís Morais Amador:
http://docentes.fe.unl.pt/~jamador/Macro/cobb-douglas.pdf
Barro, R. J.,
& Redlick, C. J. (2011). Macroeconomic Effects From Government Purchases
and Taxes. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 51-102.
Evans, O.,
& Kenward, L. (1988). Macroeconomic Effects of Tax Reform in the United
States. Staff Papers - International Monetary Fund, 141-165.
Federal Reserve
Bank of St. Louis. (2014, February 2). Civilian Labor Force Participation
Rate (CIVPART). Retrieved February 2, 2014, from Federal Reserve Economic
Data: http://research.stlouisfed.org/fred2/series/CIVPART
Feldstein, M.
(1995). The Effect of Marginal Tax Rates on Taxable Income: A Panel Study of
the 1986 Tax Reform Act. Journal of Political Economy, 551-572.
Heim, B. T.
(2009). The Effect of Recent Tax Changes on Taxable Income: Evidence from a
New Panel of Tax Returns. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management,
147-163.
Kuznets, S.
(1955). Economic Growth and Income Inequality. The American Economic Review,
1-30.
McDaniel, C.
(2011). Forces Shaping Hours Worked in the OECD, 1960-2004. American
Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 27-52.
Plumer, B.
(2013, December 5). Is inequality bad for economic growth? Retrieved
from Wonkblog: http://www.washingtonpost.com/blogs/wonkblog/wp/2013/12/05/is-inequality-bad-for-economic-growth/
No comments:
Post a Comment